Why the California Raisins Have Stopped Singing

Posted by Kimbell 9 years, 10 months ago to Government
7 comments | Share | Best of... | Flag

Why the California Raisins Have Stopped Singing
Using 1930s-era regulations, the USDA can commandeer up to half a farmer's harvest.
• Email
• Print
• 13 Comments

• Facebook
• Twitter

• Google+
• LinkedIn
• smaller

• Larger
By
JAMES BOVARD
May 26, 2014 7:18 p.m. ET
Earlier this month the Ninth U.S. Circuit Court of Appeals ruled that the U.S. Department of Agriculture taking 47% of a farmer's harvest does not violate the Fifth Amendment's takings clause as long as the government aims to drive up crop prices. The May 9 decision was the latest absurdity in a decade-long legal battle pitting California raisin growers Marvin and Lena Horne against the USDA's outmoded raisin regulatory regime.
Under current law, the 1930s-era federally authorized Raisin Administrative Committee can commandeer up to half of a farmer's harvest as a "reserve"—to purportedly stabilize markets and prevent gluts. The Hornes were fined almost $700,000 for refusing to surrender control of 47% of their 2002 harvest to the government committee and 30% of the harvest the following year. After judges declared that the Hornes could not sue in federal court for unjust takings—i.e., government confiscation without just compensation—the case landed in the Supreme Court.
Last June the Supreme Court unanimously ruled that California raisin growers have standing to file a takings claim in federal court. Even liberal justices were amazed at the heavy-handed, archaic nature of the regulatory regime. During oral arguments, JusticeStephen Breyer declared: "I can't believe that Congress wanted the taxpayers to pay for a program that's going to mean they have to pay higher prices as consumers." JusticeElena Kagan suggested that the statute authorizing the raisin cartel could be "the world's most outdated law."
Writing as if they were inspired by Justice Kagan's quip, the Ninth Circuit panel reached back a hundred years to justify perpetuating federal control of the raisin business. The decision declared, "Raisin prices rose rapidly between 1914 and 1920, peaking in 1921 at $235 per ton.
This surge in prices spurred increased production, which in turn caused prices to plummet back down to between $40 and $60 per ton." Crop prices skyrocketed during those years in large part because the World War I-era U.S. Food Administration cornered markets and vastly inflated demand by providing cheap credit to European allies to purchase boatloads of harvests. Federal intervention spurred a boom and bust that ravaged American farmers in the early 1920s.
Enlarge Image

Farmworkers pick paper trays of dried raisins off the ground and heap them onto a trailer in the final step of raisin harvest in 2013. Associated Press
The Agricultural Marketing Agreement Act of 1937 authorized the secretary of Agriculture to appoint farmer-dominated committees to control production. The subsequent crop marketing orders were based on the New Deal philosophy of "managed abundance"—prosperity through "universal monopoly and universal scarcity." The Ninth Circuit decision quotes a 1943 Supreme Court ruling justifying regimenting raisin farmers because the industry became "compelled to sell at less than parity prices."
But the parity index was concocted by government agricultural economists in the 1920s to justify federal aid to farmers. "Parity" was based on a set ratio of farm prices to nonfarm prices, in correlation with the ratio that prevailed in 1910-14, a boom time for farmers. Because production costs for both farm and nonfarm goods radically changed, it never made any economic sense to rely on "parity" but it was a popular political ploy.
The Ninth Circuit judges' curiosity seemingly never extended beyond reading USDA press releases. Their decision this month declared that "the Marketing Order ensures 'orderly' market conditions by regulating raisin supply." But the raisin committee's sweeping powers have failed to prevent vast swings in prices farmers receive. Many California farmers have shifted their land to other crops; the acreage devoted to raisin production has plunged since 2000. The Ninth Circuit effectively declared that a taking is not a taking if the government intends to benefit the victim, regardless of how much damage the government inflicts.
The judges played down the Hornes' losses because they only involved "personal property"—not "real property" such as land. This is a slippery distinction that at least one other federal appeals court has utterly rejected. The decision stressed that the "Hornes did not lose all economically valuable use of their personal property," presumably since the feds did not take all their raisins.
The judges noted that "the Hornes can avoid the reserve requirement . . . by planting different crops" not subject to federally authorized commandeering. Supreme Court Justice Antonin Scalia captured the reality far better when he said in oral arguments in March 2013 that the USDA in effect offers farmers a choice: "Your raisins or your life."
The Ninth Circuit decision illustrates how judicial docility and economic illiteracy can vest boundless power in bureaucracies. The Hornes will likely appeal to the Supreme Court. This could potentially result in a landmark takings ruling that finally torpedoes the raisin regime and numerous other USDA cartels.
Mr. Bovard is the author, among other books, "Attention Deficit Democracy" (Palgrave, 2006) and "Lost Rights: The Destruction of American Liberty" (St. Martin's, 1994).


Add Comment

FORMATTING HELP

All Comments Hide marked as read Mark all as read

  • Comment hidden by post owner or admin, or due to low comment or member score. View Comment
  • Posted by Maphesdus 9 years, 10 months ago
    Driving up prices by artificially limiting supply? Now that's an act of tyranny if there ever was one. I think this calls for a new Constitutional Amendment...

    ––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––
    Hypothetical Amendment XXVIII:
    "The right of the people to determine the supply and price of commodities and react to the natural flow of supply and demand in the market, free from government interference by means of artificial limitations, controls, and/or demands imposed on supply and/or price, shall not be infringed."
    ––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––––

    Who's with me?
    Reply | Mark as read | Best of... | Permalink  
  • Posted by 9 years, 10 months ago
    There are many more instances, the Hornes are only one, one with the guts to fight for sure. Too bad they are against a loaded hand with this Supreme Court.
    Reply | Mark as read | Best of... | Permalink  

FORMATTING HELP

  • Comment hidden. Undo